唯寻国际教育旗下指定官方网站
课程咨询热线 400-825-6055
留学关键节点

ALEVEL经济学员必读 英国经济论文竞赛获奖文章分析

ALEVEL资料
经济AS套题
AL经济真题
AL化学AS套题
AL化学考纲分析
AL高数考纲分析
CIE AS化学重难点
点击领取
12-10
唯寻杯

ALEVEL经济学想读好,阅读材料积累不能少。本文将分享英国最大的经济写作竞赛之一英国皇家经济学会的获奖文章解析。想知道它的内容好在哪儿吗?想知道里面提到了哪些ALEVEL经济学知识点吗?想为考试攒结构和模板句吗?赶快下拉查收吧。

 ALEVEL经济学员必读 英国经济论文竞赛获奖文章分析内容图片_1

(获奖经济文章来源:

以下例文摘自The Royal Economic Society -Winners of the young economist of the year 2018- Best overall essay

  Dan Gilbey – Haberdashers Askes Boys School)

获奖文章原文

  RES Essay Competition Dan Gilbey

  Does economics have the answer for the global problem of plastics pollution?

  Part I – Does Economics have the Solution to the Global Problem of Plastics Pollution?

  To best answer this question, we must, perhaps, look at possible answers under the following criteria:

  1. Can the policy be implemented on a global scale?

  2. Does the policy only reduce future consumption, without reversing the effects of past and present consumption, and vice versa?

  3. How sustainable is the solution, and does it cause unwanted and unintended negative consequences?

  In its most basic form, the problem is external costs(1). We can internalise these by appealing to people’s sentiments, or, as this essay will focus on, appealing to pockets and using price systems to influence market signals. Coase argued that market failures(2) occur because of a lack of sufficient property rights and high transaction costs, which would otherwise lead to a ‘fair’ allocation of resources (Coase, 1960). If we can establish comprehensive property rights in transactions, and reduce transaction costs, we can eliminate the market failure as economic agents will interact with each other to yield a socially optimal level of consumption and production. This is already being used in the form of tradeable  permits(1),such as the EU Emission Trading Scheme. A central authority determines the ‘safe’ maximum level of pollution, issuing permits which limit the amount of pollution that can be produced in an area. Though only currently being used for emissions pollution, such as SO2, a similar system could be established for plastics. Permits force those involved in the transaction to ‘internalise’ the external cost of pollution. Maximising the effect of this solution, requires finding the major sources of plastic pollution. These are:

  ▼ Fishing equipment (Hammer, Kraak and Parsons, 2012) and,

  ▼Single-use plastic packaging and bags (Barnes et al., 2009). Knowing this, it is possible to assign tradeable plastic permits to three major groups:

  ▼Firms who produce plastic goods and/or use them in their production process, e.g. requiring that firms declare the amount of plastic entering their factories.

  ▼Consumers who buy products which contain plastic in some form, e.g. issuing permits required to be used when buying products with plastic and tracking the total weight of plastic bought over a given time period.

  ▼ Commercial fishermen who use plastic equipment e.g. requiring a card which debits plastic usage credits when they buy plastic fishing equipment This would mean that a controlled amount of plastic is both produced and consumed, at a minimal cost to society – this is because permits are: • sold by those who get the least value from them, as using little plastic has a relatively low opportunity cost, and • bought by those who value them the most, reducing the opportunity cost involved in limiting their usage or production of it. Moreover, permits could be issued on a global scale, by an international organisation, such as the UN. Not only do permits directly limit pollution, but they cause economic agents to be more careful in choosing and reusing what they buy. Tradeable permits are sustainable, take direct action against the problem and deliver one solution, sourced in economic theory, to solve the global problem of plastics pollution. A benefit of tradable permits is that their effectiveness has already been proven. Taking Chile as one example of a country which implemented the scheme in 1992 to cut emissions, we can see that from 1997 to 2005, aggregate emissions (kg/day) fell from 2544.79 to 688.51 (Coria and Sterner, 2009). While their use has mainly been focussed on emissions, their success supports implementing them for plastic as well. The key weakness with tradable permits under the original criteria is that they only help reduce future pollution but do nothing to reverse the effects of past pollution.

  Alternatively, we could find another solution by using Pigou’s explanation of the problem of externalities. Because external effects are not accounted for in production costs or individual utility functions, they are also not subsequently reflected in product pricing (Pigou, 1933), meaning plastics are too cheap both to make and buy, therefore becoming both over-produced and over-consumed. We could, therefore, consider imposing Pigouvian taxes on plastics. Not only would these reduce the supply of plastics as their production costs become higher, but it would also reduce the quantity of plastics demanded, as consumers move away from pricier plastic-heavy products, e.g. in the packaging. Hence, taxes(2) are a cost-effective way of reducing the quantity of plastics entering the environment. There is, however, a case against the use of taxes to discourage consumption and production of a certain good. In the case of cigarettes, a recent study has suggested that a tax would be needed in order to reduce adult smoking by just 5% (Callison and Kaestner, 2013), indicating that taxes are not always efficient at ensuring an outcome, as they rely on many other factors. The success of a tax specifically on plastic depends on whether the tax makes plastic more expensive than alternatives (which may be difficult given how cheap it currently is) as well as the demand-price elasticity of the product.

  A similar policy would simply be to introduce a surcharge(3) on plastic goods (Nilsen, 2010). This idea comes from simple demand economics; increase the price of a good, demand will fall. Additionally, because retailers often give the money to charity, the higher price of the product will not incentivise higher supply, because the retailers are not using the bags to seek profit-maximisation, as neo-classical economics would assume. The model of the supply-curve would no longer function, rather we would just see a horizontal supply curve. Five years after China’s introduction of a surcharge on ultra-thin plastic bags in 2005, it was found that there had already been a reduction of plastic bags used by 67,000,000,000. It is too early to judge the long-term impact of the policy. There is a chance that, in time, the extra cost will be absorbed by consumers, impacting the sustainability of the policy.

  Ideas from behavioural economics may solve the problem, specifically that people are averse to losses(4) (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). Introducing a loss to people who do not recycle, could dramatically increase recycling. If recycling units were put in building entrances around major cities, and in stores, which give a small percentage of the original price of the product back to the consumer if they put their old plastic bottles in the unit, we could incentivise the recycling of plastics. Introducing a private cost to those who do not recycle their plastics, creates a loss of not recycling. Importantly, the money returned must exceed the opportunity cost of collecting it. In Germany this is being used for plastic bottles where 90% are recycled, compared to 57% of plastic bottles in the UK. Through the use of the UN to implement such a strategy on a global scale could be an effective way of combatting the plastic problem.

  Part II: What can we therefore conclude?

  Taxes and charges on plastics can be effective, but really only in the short-run, as over time, people absorb this extra price. These leaves tradable permits and cash-back systems as two potential solutions to plastic pollution.

  ▼Looking at the global nature of the policies, cash-back systems require investment into the infrastructure to allow the systems to be put in. Such an investment may not be the most efficient use of money in developing nations, where capital is scarce. With tradable permits, while it can be implemented on a global scale, the bigger question is whether it can be enforced. There are too many companies for all of them to report to the UN, hence national governments must pay a role in moderating and enforcing the permits, something very difficult to do in a developing nation where corruption may be rife.

  ▼With the temporal scale of the solution, tradable permits are an efficient way of reducing future consumption but do nothing to reverse the effects of previous pollution. While cash-back systems do not necessarily clear up landfill sites, they can impact waste in people’s homes otherwise bound for landfill.

  ▼Tradable permits have low implementation and enforcement costs meaning that government failure is less likely to occur. Cash-back systems are unlikely to deliver a complete change in cultural attitudes to recycling. However, the maintenance costs of this system are minimal, even if the setup costs are large, supporting sustainability over long periods. One weakness with the system is that if it were to be removed, the effect on recycling in the future is likely to reverse; if people no longer get money back for recycling, they are unlikely to still recycle. Conversely, with tradable permits, the process of not producing or using much plastic among economic agents becomes habitual. Despite their flaws, a combination of the cash-back and tradable permit systems would be an effective economic solution to plastic pollution. Solutions from economic theory which reduce future plastic production and consumption are available to provide part of the solution to the global problem of plastics pollution.

获奖文章文章解析

这篇获奖作文是非常标准的学术派经济作文的写作方法。

文章的部分分析塑料污染的原因external costs(1),以及会出现的问题market failures(2),并提出4个解决方法tradeable permits(1),taxes(2),surcharge(3),averse to losses(4) 即cash-back,每一个解决方法都给出充分的分析,这个方法是如何解决market failure问题的,最后在文章的第二部分对这4个方法进行了evaluation,这4个方法是在短期有效还是长期有效,以及这四个方法的优点和缺陷。

希望这篇文章能给各位ALEVEL经济学人带来灵感,如果觉得有用,就把它收到你的私人素材库吧。

最后提醒下大家,虽然2020ALEVEL的高分率高到离谱,拿到A*的学员占了14.3%,A及以上分数的学员接近40%,但这都是今年的特殊情况造成的。如果想在明年乃至未来的考试中脱颖而出,只有细致的复习和学习才是捷径。标化成绩是所有大学申请的敲门砖,如果你想早日抵达目标大学分数线,点击报名【唯寻AELVE同步培训班】——

海归执教  

研发教学系统

层层“吃透”官方题库

“阶梯式”教学激发学员动力

培养学员世界知名大学要求的学习力

 ALEVEL经济学员必读 英国经济论文竞赛获奖文章分析内容图片_2

 ALEVEL经济学员必读 英国经济论文竞赛获奖文章分析内容图片_3

 ALEVEL经济学员必读 英国经济论文竞赛获奖文章分析内容图片_4

更多ALEVEL学习攻略点击

ALEVEL经济真题Essay范文解析 出题人的言外之意你能get到吗    

ALEVEL经济怎么复习才能拿A* 一定要重视图形理解    


唯寻杯
关于ALEVEL课程的困惑,您来问我为您解答!
Stephy Tian唯寻ALEVEL课程产品经理
是上海较早一批就读A-level的学生,以A*AA的优异成绩毕业于上师大剑桥国际中心(现领科国际学校);田老师从2017年开始全职加入国际教育行业。
微信咨询

快扫码
关注老师微信

在线咨询
留学资料免费领取
开启buff留学之路
  • 英美留学规划时间轴
  • 牛剑面试sample
  • 牛津数学系面试真题解析
  • 剑桥雅思官方真题集
  • 33所大学申请指南
  • 牛津大学留学指南
  • 美国大学10年录取形势变化统计报告
  • 剑桥大学留学指南
  • QS300英国院校指南合集
  • 更多留学资料
立即领取
唯寻导师团队

潘田翰(创始人)

剑桥大学化学工程硕士

Candise Cai

牛津大学化学硕士

Chris Chen

帝国理工学院物理学士

Ruby Rui

剑桥大学经济系学士&双硕士学位

Elaine Xu

牛津大学数学与统计专业学士

Olivia Hu

纽卡斯尔大学语言学专业硕士

Irene Liu

约翰霍普金斯大学国际关系/国际经济硕士

Mini Liu

东南密苏里州立大学双硕士

Shanshan Yu

英国伦敦政治经济学院金融学硕士

Stephy Tian

帝国理工化学硕士

Max Liu

帝国理工大学生物病毒学硕士

Sherry Lu

剑桥大学教育语言学硕士

Sue Pang

牛津大学经济与管理学士学位&LSE硕士

Jaryn Huang

牛津大学社会人类学专业哲学硕士

Peter Liu

牛津大学工程科学专业学士&硕士

Frances Zhu

牛津大学化学专业学士&硕士

Qianli Xia

剑桥大学数学系荣誉学士&硕士

Fang Yuan

美国普渡大学生物工程荣誉学士

Freda Yang

伦敦大学学院应用语言学硕士

Bo Su

范德堡大学英语教育硕士

Yuchen Yang

剑桥大学化学工程专业学士&硕士

Dora Liang

华威大学硕士

Tiffany Lin

伦敦大学学院经济学硕士
唯寻业务优势
  • 专业做牛剑/G5申请、牛剑笔面试培训,案例多数据全,经验丰富,筑梦牛剑/G5。
  • 众多牛剑+藤校等TOP院校背景导师,为您打造专属留学方案。英美留学绿色通道,个性规划,便捷申请。
  • 顾问师/规划师/课程导师/助教四位一体线上+线下服务闭环,让家长和学员放心。学习有方法,成长看得见。
  • ALevel/IB/AP/IGCSE国际课程辅导,牛剑/G5/藤校留学申请,竞赛背提培训,标化语言考试一体化服务。
荣誉源于实力
留学教育行业"全国知名度"品牌机构
Oxford International AQA Approved Teaching School
雅思考试合作伙伴项目明日之星
荣获新浪《年度品牌影响力国际教育机构》
荣获腾讯《年度影响力在线教育品牌》
荣获新华社《口碑影响力课外辅导机构》
National Economics challenge 2020 Official Test Center
2018年度家长信赖在线教育品牌

在线抢试听名额

学习有方法,成长看得见

筑梦牛剑/G5/常春藤

立即领取
相关文章推荐
唯寻导师推荐
换一换

Sue Pang

牛津大学经济与管理学士学位&LSE硕士

牛津大学圣埃德蒙学院 经济与管理学士学位&LSE硕士

· 2011-2014 牛津圣埃德蒙学院经济与管理本科 2:1学位

· 2015-2016 伦敦政治经济学院经济与管理硕士 Merit

· 新加坡A-level体系(Raffles),高中曾参加过各类别标化考试:TOEFL 118, AP 4科五分,SAT1 2200, SAT2 2400

· 曾在Royal Bank of Scotland, Goldman Sachs投行部实习经历; 伦敦Fine Arts College教授A-level经济一年

立即领取